A Crowdfunding Agency Model for Renewables in an Emerging Economy

Un modelo basado en agencia para financiamiento crowdfunding de energías renovables en una economía emergente

 

Cecilia Castro-Cárdenas[1], Alejandro Ibarra-Yunez[2]

 

Abstract

 

Mobilizing finance for investment in renewable energy is a challenge for climate change mitigation via fostering the layout of new projects. The challenge becomes critical in emerging or developing economies, mainly because the architecture of financial intermediaries as well as their instruments are shallow and insufficiently developed. The present investigation reviews alternative vehicles of finance applied specifically to renewable energies, that are intermittent, so-called non-dispatchable, and innovation- plus capital-intensive, as compared to conventional sources. The high degree of investment irreversibility and with relatively high uncertainty in the regulatory and wholesale market, calls to carefully design origins of finance at the government, private, and mixed levels. An agency-based theoretical framework is proposed within our ongoing research effort that includes green banks, state banks, bonds, and mainly, crowdfunding, that could be applied to Mexico.

 

Key Words: Investment & Capacity; Renewable Energy; Crowdfunding.

 

Resumen

 

La movilización de financiamiento para la inversión en energías renovables es un desafío para la mitigación del cambio climático a través del desarrollo de nuevos proyectos. El desafío se vuelve crítico en las economías emergentes o en desarrollo, principalmente por la arquitectura de los intermediarios financieros, así como sus instrumentos, los cuáles son superficiales e insuficientemente desarrollados. La presente investigación analiza vehículos alternativos de financiamiento aplicados específicamente a energías renovables, que son intermitentes, llamadas no despachables, e intensivas en innovación y capital, en comparación con las fuentes convencionales. El alto grado de irreversibilidad de las inversiones y con una incertidumbre relativamente alta en el mercado regulado y mayorista, llama a diseñar cuidadosamente los orígenes del financiamiento a nivel gubernamental, privado y mixto. Dentro de nuestro esfuerzo de investigación en curso, se propone un marco teórico basado en la teoría de agencia que incluye bancos verdes, bancos estatales, bonos y, principalmente, crowdfunding, que podría aplicarse a México.

 

Palabras Clave: Inversión y capacidad; Energías renovables; Crowdfunding.

 

JEL Classification: D25; Q42; G23

 

Introduction and justification

There is a seminal question of financing renewable energy projects in the case of developed versus developing economies, mainly because in the latter, financial institutions and instruments are argued to be shallower and projects face relatively higher regulatory and market risks than on the former developed countries. The question has consequences in the welfare front and the quest to solve the asymmetry of economic bases, financial instruments, and financing strategies. Critical points need to be spelled out to create a framework not only on the institutions of energy markets and their risks, but also focused on financial strategies and instruments to both promote investment in renewable generation (wind, solar, clean co-generation, mini-hydro, tidal, etc.), while securing financial soundness in financing strategies and instruments. The present investigation specifically addresses types of financing to optimize financing returns from financial strategies, while promoting such investments, applied specifically to two renewable technologies: solar-pv, and wind.

The paper is organized as follows: After framing the critical literature on both renewables markets and their dynamics in the literature, plus main addressing of financial conditions for renewable project financing in the next section, section 3 frames the problem handoff financing small renewable projects, mainly in developing markets. Section 4 spells out an agency-based theoretical model between project development and alternative financing and presents theoretical propositions. Section 5 explores some empirics of the on-going research, while Section 6 concludes.

 

Literature review

 

The Electricity and Renewables Markets and their Dynamics

After many years of a vertically integrated incumbent utility, many countries embarked in vertically separating competitive areas of electricity generation, self-supply, commercialization and trading, and the development of an independent system operator (ISO) to promote development of renewable energies, mainly since the beginning of the 21st century (Bieleki 2004; Hogan, IRENA 2018; Rosellón, and Vogelsang 2010; IEA 2018; Rosellón, Myslikova, and Zenon 2011; Wolak, 2005). Vertical separation began in developed economies in the eighties (i.e. the UK), but soon after, it was also applied to a bundle of developing countries (i.e. Chile, Argentina, and Mexico in Latin America).

The beginning of deregulated markets gave a key role to the regulator to apply asymmetric rules for the monopolistic part of the (wholesale) markets, while it promoted a wholesale market with many participants in an increasing atomized environment and increasing number of renewable producers, consumers, and traders. Such focus has been addressed by many (EIA 2011; Griffin and Puller 2005; Ibarra-Yunez 2017; Maurer and Barroso 2011 on auctions as an effective vehicle to promote new investments; OFGEM 2010 on the UK deregulation; Pollitt 2012, on challenges in asymmetric deregulation; Stoft 2006 on vertical disintegration models).

The dynamics and strategic space for renewable sources of energy and the role of non-conventional generation has increasingly been studied. However, given technology and market development, hurdles for the renewable, intermittent, hence non-dispatchable generation has also been stressed by recent studies such as Bunn and Muñoz (2015); Bushnell, and Novan (2018); Egerer, and Schill (2014) on the conditioning of generation by transmission and interconnection market failure; Egerer, Rosellón, and Schill (2015), on regulatory incentives for renewables, but also IEA (2018), and, more recently, IRENA (2020),

Moreover, on regulatory and market failure models, authors that have addressed welfare deviation phenomena include Bushnell, Mansur, and Saravia (2008), on the dynamics of new market arrangements; Höfner and Cranz (2011) on legal unbundling imperfections; Jamasb and Pollitt (2005), on applications to Europe; Joskow (2005) for an application to the California market failure of 2003; Joskow (2008) on the future of liberalization; Kwoka (2008) on the US restructuring; Matsuyama (1990) on imperfect and conditional investment; and Pollitt (2012) on the soundness of an independent system operator (ISO/ RTO).

Recent scientific contributions have increasingly used agency-based approaches to emphasize asymmetric objectives and incentives of renewable projects between investment owners and promoters, as opposed to funding incentives and institutions. Examples are Van der Berg, & Tempels (2022) for a case study in the Netherlands; and Martinez-Climent (2021) for a model in Spain.

The promotion and dynamics of clean energy and non-conventional renewable energy projects by technology, and the means to promote their uptake has been addressed by fewer authors. However, the subject has been framed and studied by seminal works from Bunn and Muñoz (2015) on intermittency as a source of financial risk on renewable projects; Mexico’s CENACE (2015) on renewables planning and launching; Europe’s THINK project (2013) applied to the uptake of renewables. Poltzin et al. (2015) studied a data panel of investments on renewables and their policy influences by technological maturity; while Ibarra-Yunez, et al. (2017), concentrated on the legal framework for solar-PV projects in California and Mexico. The present research and contribution aim to close the agent-based approach to projects in alternative financing. For that purpose, a further brief review of the finance literature follows.

 

The financial strategy, institutional development, and instruments of financing non-conventional project development.

Fewer research has addressed the paucity of analyses for asymmetric settings between developed and developing economies (Liming,2009; Kutan, Paramati, Ummalla, and Zakari, 2017) mainly because the strength and maturity of financial institutions (banks and non-banks), and their instruments of financing small scale renewable projects, characterized by their intermittent character, are starkly different in that they need to internalize relatively higher financial, economic, and policy risks to these projects. In them policy plays a key role as a complement origin of both finance (subsidies policies, feed-in tariffs in Europe, tax policy applied to promote renewables uptake in investment projects, venture capital as financial options), and deregulation and asymmetric regulation by project layers or echelons.

Very recently, Mazzucato and Semieniuk (2018) studied several types of financial actors (including private banks, public banks, private utilities, and public utilities) and created a risk measure based on technology and market risk exposure to the financial actors, given their investment portfolio across technologies and countries. Some other authors have analyzed the relationship between policy and renewal energy deployment in several different ways, some of which develop game-theoretical mathematical models. Main contributions include Delmas and Montes-Sancho, 2011; Harmelink, Voogt and Cremer, 2006; Jacobsson, Bergek, Finon, Lauber, Mitchell, Toke and Verbruggen, 2009; Menz and Vachon, 2006.

However, only a few quantitative analyses address the influence of public policies on investments in clean energy by private institutional investors (Bolkesjø, Eltvig and Nygaard, 2014; Chassot, Hampl and Wüstenhagen, 2014; Lüthi and Prässler, 2011; Lüthi and Wüstenhagen, 2012). Other alternative mechanisms such as government feed-in tariffs have been recently studied about their effectiveness and efficiency, mainly at the load part of the market, i.e., the demand part (Carley, 2009; Lesser and Su, 2008; Mathews, Kidney, Mallon and Hughes, 2010).

In contrast, others concentrate on subsidies as a support instrument that provide fiscal relief for renewal energy projects, mainly in the early stages of the technology development (Olmos, Ruester and Liong, 2012; Bergek, Mignon and Sundberg, 2013). Finally, new alternative mechanisms of private investment or alternatives mixed with public support, such as crowdfunding, social funds, green banks, and green bonds, have been used to help policy makers and renewal energy drivers, investors and project owners. Main referent papers are Yildiz (2014) who studied financial citizen participation in Germany; Lam et al. (2016) analyzed precisely the crowdfunding alternative for clean energy innovations and projects; Mathews and Kidney (2012) reviewed private sector involvement through the green bonds market, while Whitney (2014) provides a theoretical model for green banks’ participation on clean energy deployment.

 

Institutional framework and mapping

An important characteristic of renewable energy deployment is that the entire process of a project implementation is affected by barriers, relating both to the inherent characteristics of innovation and technological change, and to environmental externalities (Jaffe, Newell and Stavins, 2005). One of the most important barriers for clean energy implementation is the financing environment, as is emphasized here. Polzin (2017) describes a framework of such factors affecting funding behavior.

 

Figure 1

Barriers and private investment participation on renewable energy deployment

Source: Polzin, F. (2017). Mobilizing private finance for low-carbon innovation. A systematic review of barriers and solutions. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews: 77, 525–535. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.04.007

 

As is shown above, Polzin describes different steps in the process of clean energy innovation and implementation, at the government policy element, contrasting project stages. Each stage implies specific barriers and risks (including the government policy of the country). In the presence of such environment behavior, different private investment mechanisms play important roles. During the first two steps (R & D), technologies are developed by public research institutes or universities as well as private firms. In the next two steps, the most difficult ones even called the “valley of death” (Polzin, 2017), capital expenses are high as well as the risks of failure in the so-called pre-commercial stage of development. Thus, private financing agents (rather principals in game theory terms), such as business angels, family offices, crowd-funders and venture capitalists are the financial providers who accept the risk involved, as opposed to other financial institutions such as banks who restrain themselves from such project financing, while green bonds are recent and need underwriting in official institutional markets, that are often weak or non-existing.

In the last two steps where the technology starts to have commercial acceptance, funds can be collected from public resources, private equity or even from banks and formal financial institutions. Financing plays a key role for renewable energy innovation, implementation and promotion. The first steps of a clean energy project imply large amounts of capital investments with high risks involved.

Also, one could address the framework of financial instruments and set difficulties and challenges for the diverse sources of financing, following a World Bank (2013) framework, as follows:

 

gree of EndogFigure 2

Financial Instruments and Deenous Risk

Source: World Bank (2013), “Financing Renewable Energy - Options for Developing Financing Instruments Using Public Funds. [Online] Available at: https://www.climateinvestmentfunds.org/cif/sites/climateinvestmentfunds.org/files/SREP_financing_instruments_sk_clean2_FINAL_FOR_PRINTING.pdf

 

As can be seen, instruments to finance renewable energy projects by main technologies, depend on the degree of development of a country in question (developed versus developing), as well as the degree of development of the renewable technology in the projects, where the start-up cost is rather high, and the average levelized cost of energy (LCOE) of the alternative projects, imply financing barriers per se or challenges in both the financial soundness and the renewable technology and country development stage.

  For example, insufficient development of financial instruments in the left column, such as venture capital, senior debt credit lines, or asset-backed securities, and green bank project financing, give rise to shallow financial backing of renewable projects. On the side of project risks, grants could be available in developed countries but much less so in developing economies. Also, project risk guarantees, project uptake insurance might not exist in some cases. All in all, the need to move behind these mentioned challenges calls for designing project finance that minimizes financial risks. Examples are stage financing, small scale financing, aggregated financing of a set of projects in a pool of renewable projects traded in the wholesale market, in what is called commercial virtual power plants CVPP, contingent project development grants where financing is provided in stages by the renewable energy projects, like a seminal contribution by Wang and Zhou (2004), or the emerging opportunities of crowdfunding as in Lam and Law (2016). Such stage financing and crowdfunding are emphasized in the present research.

 

Theoretical model and equilibrium

 

Theoretical Model

Framing a renewable energy project owner (REP) implies to invest in a solar (or wind) farm that is capital intensive. Assume also a project financier, for example a crowdfunder providing green investment (CF); both players are risk averse. Then, assume an electrical utility for both backup and procuring green energy products for the REP that is assumed to be risk neutral and passive in the present framework (alternative scenarios of incumbent playing a blockading role could also be modeled elsewhere in the research effort, as a third player). Let a game theoretical approach be followed as the preferred model, because of asymmetric objectives between the players, time asymmetries, and the risk inclusion.

The game between the REP and the CF should have a time asymmetry character since one cannot assume immediate funding to integrate risk bearing in a finite-conditional funding in stages. The game frame can be seen as follows: at time  REP calculates CAPEX/OPEX investment and expected return of the project, both on-grid with the electricity utility or else off-grid if REP opts for self-supply of some sort (behind the meter; with net metering; net billing of full merchant business). At    CF decides for full funding, conditional stage funding or no funding. REP receives full or partial funds. Project returns are observed at  with CF receiving repayment, and REP observing her net revenue (see Tirole 1988).

 

Figure 3 Timeline of the game process between REP and CF

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Source: own generation

Time space of the REP is determined by  The same applies to CF of stage financing  or full   . Risk factors are denoted by   Demand is a given and it is assumed that all REP output (  is sold either off-grid on a private contract or with net metering with the utility at the market basic price of $/MWh.

Following Zheng Ying-Xu, Chakraborty and Sycara (2015), the utility provides energy to consumers with demand  with mean . It can buy green energy from the REP at wholesale price  and resell to the market at market price  with mean  . Let  be the supply of green energy. Putting for the moment the utility at the center of the argument, the total procurement cost is shown as follows where the utility seeks to minimize such cost:

Now the active REP supply  depends on the investment effort by the project seekers. Say investment is measured by the total number of panels installed or wind-farm towers installed,   . Let  be the total cost of investing, purchasing, permits, installation costs and maintenance costs in each of the 3 periods. Moreover  where  is the individual unit panel (tower) cost and  in the allocated costs per period. Each unit generates an uncertain amount of green energy   .

Let’s assume that the uncertain green output  is represented for now with a normal distribution (no heavy tails) with mean  and standard deviation of   . Total green supply is   . Thus, the expected risk, and the investment cost  can be assumed continuous after period   of the financing game. Let’s assume that the contract between a REP and CF is by the REP offering a contract for CF. Contract can be seen as follows:

The REP´s decision program is to maximize funding/output in the market: 

 

    On its part, the CF payoff to maximize follows from the above as:

 

Where  is the level of investment of the REP. Hence, one can allow for either one shot funding or stage financing (Wang and Zhou, 2002). The utility function of risk averse from the REP follows a Constant Absolute Risk Aversion (CARA) utility. This function assumes a  risk tolerance degree of the REP. As Wang et al. describe, the REP chooses the level of investment expecting to maximize the utility with a contract with the CF.

 

  REP risk aversion utility        

 

 

Equilibrium

Given all the setting described above, consider the options: a) no crowdfunding; b) full crowdfunding with a risk assumption; c) crowdfunding stage funding with risk assumption in stages.

 

No crowdfunding

In the base case, the utility determines wholesale prices  and the REP chooses investment level  to supply to the utility by optimal investment. In this case  is cero. Thus, the risk averse REP invests to get a total net revenue (profit) of:

 

REP:

 

For the utility, it chooses the wholesale price that minimizes the expected procurement cost.

 

So, the optimal = argmin.

 

Crowdfunding in one shot form

Additional to the REP self-funding  , CF invests in the project at the rate of financing  part of the entire project N. REP decides to optimize investment with a return   given the contract offered to CF, then it will derive the optimal contract  and investment decision     where then the utility will derive its optimal new  assuming that funding will imply more investment commitment by the REP.

For the CF, each investor payoff under investment decision ( ) is  in each period since   The optimal CF will include the mean adjusted investment and integrate the total risk.

Stage/conditional funding

Then the CF sends all part of the risk factor of the maximization towards the REP, that needs to forecast each stage 1,2,3 net revenues from investing

With the above alternatives, one could further the following hypotheses:

 

Hypothesis 1.- In the case of no crowdfunding, the REP will face the wholesale price set by the utility wt and will be increasing in energy generated (scale of the REP), and the funding the utility is willing to pay, given its own cost minimization E [c0 (w)]. The cutoff equilibrium will be w*

Hypothesis 2.- In the case of funding on one shot, the utility will face a wholesale price requirement w** < w* to cover its relationship with the REP, meaning that the CF becomes the active participant principal of the REP agent. For the REP, it will invest in the renewable project N*0 (w) depending now on the amount of funds from the CF, and investment costs.

Hypothesis 3.- In the case of full financing, the CF principal will offer the funds in period 2 that integrate the net expected revenue from the REP agent, with the project risk subtracted from net REP revenues. The assumed risk for the REP will be declining in investment effort and investment costs.

Hypothesis 4.- In the case of stage financing, REP investment will increase in conditional stages by the CF principal. Stage funds are increasing as REP risk is decreasing in the stages. For the CF, the reduced risk from the investment project Bt , will mean higher return E ( ), than full financing E ( ). Repayment directly depends on finance (and investment) effort.

 

Empirical framework for a workable case

Since around 2010, renewable energy efforts have increased mainly due to the abatement of the weighted average cost of capital (WACC), additional to REP and CF project risk. According to IRENA (2018), one weight that is acceptable is a 7.5% for OECD countries while the WACC could easily reach around 10% for the rest of the world, without considering exchange rate volatility.

Now, taking IRENA’s global calculation of the various emerging renewable technologies and their average costs, they range for 2017, from around US$2,000 for large PV-solar, to US$3,700 for small (below .5 MW) per kW. For wind projects, average levelized cost ranges from US$1,200 to US$1,700 per kW. For combined cycle investment (CC-gas projects), it is around US$1,000 per kW, while for hydropower ranges from US$1,000 to US$3,500 per kW. As can be seen, renewables have become rather competitive in installation costs, and cannot be seen as too expensive. Moreover, energy efficiency indexes have increased to around 20% - even 40% which avoids one main criticism to renewable projects.

Given the above cost of capital and installations, or CAPEX, the OPEX in 2017, according to the firm Lazard (2017), before subsidies and tax credits, wind comes as the cheapest with operating costs of between US$30-60 per MWh, then comes large solar-PV OPEX at around US$43-53 /MWh, while combined cycle, or CC costs range from US$42 to US$78 / MWh, while coal is at least at the level of US$ 60 /MWh (Lazard 2017). Figures for latest 2021 are not readily available due to economic disruptions arising from the world COVID-19 pandemic. However, one can check the abatement of costs in renewables for 2021 to be around 35%. Most small REP projects range from around USD$ 70,000 to about USD$ 500,000 overall in 2015 (Zheng et a. 2015).

Main risks of renewables, as has been stressed in the present research have to do first with the intermittency of REP that increase financial risks; the size of RE projects, that could stay small and not attaining minimum efficient scale to be partially funded, mainly by non-banks. The most important sources of risk for REP to enter the market seem to arise from incumbent utilities with high market power that could discriminate against or even negate interconnection against renewable projects, mainly if the wholesale market participant is weak. Then another source is the wholesale price w, w* and w**. Hence, small project funding ones, as crowdfunding and other competing sources (ex. green bonds), can be justified.

Additionally, another source of risk comes from regulatory failure, meaning that the regulator fails to provide predictable and clear regulatory instruments to promote the expansion of markets and investments (Ibarra-Yunez 2017). The above has been evidenced more starkly by Mexico’s central government decisions that have derailed renewable economic incentives (not modeled in the present analysis but could change in future administrations).

One needs to note that from the pure cost comparisons there seems that REP is not at a disadvantage, except that the upfront CAPEX poses a time asymmetry for the project risks (CAPEX is somewhat higher in REP than fossil sources, but with much lower OPEX than traditional fossil sources). According to IRENA (2019), the global weighted average cost of electricity from onshore wind, fell 23% between 2010 and 2017 to around US$40 /MWh, mainly driven by turbine cost declines.

Recent auctions have occurred in many countries such as Canada, Germany, the US, and Poland among developed economies, and in Brazil, Chile, Mexico (until 2019), Morocco, and Saudi-Arabia, among developing ones. Auctions seem to become a well-regarded means to promote REP uptake, mainly for the following reasons: a) they attract investors; b) leveling the competitive field if regulation is transparent and purposeful; c) triggering asymmetric pro-market regulation in those market parts that are not natural monopolies; and d) auctions have lowered the offered costs.

A case can be built with experiences between developed and developing examples and hurdles. Noteworthy is that onshore wind power LCOEs were as low as US$0.03/ kWh, with average capacity factors reaching the mentioned 30% by 2018, both in developed but mostly in developing economies (IRENA 2018). With the above framework, one can simulate REP as an ongoing research exercise in a future research effort.

To conclude the present section, the next figures exemplify the cost reduction of renewable energy by technology, the global average size of capacity and energy installations, capital costs, and renewable uptake comparisons.

 

Source: IRENA. 2020. Data file renewable power generation costs.

 

Source: IRENA. 2020. Data file renewable power generation costs.

 

Conclusions

The present article analyzes the main financing vehicles funding renewable energy projects, mainly considering the risks involved, the specific and intensive capital needs and the institutional barriers. Emerging economies also provide different ecosystems that increase the risks perceived and impact investor’s perspectives, as sources of finance and renewable projects face differences with developed economies.

A game theoretical model is presented capturing the financing process between a private capital investor (Crowdfunding CF), an electricity utility, and the renewable energy project owner (REP) from a group of funding options: no funding, full funding or stage (conditional) financing. Equilibria and outflows are modeled per scenario and analyzed considering all the players.

Finally, an analysis of a future workable case is provided in order to identify the future applications and research paths to be followed to increase the existing literature in the matter of innovate financing mechanisms for clean energy deployment in emerging economies. No sufficient data can be found, but a research set of hypotheses grants the treatment of the research effort. Limitations to be addressed in future research, that are not addressed here, are a) risk behaves in a static manner with a normal probability distribution that can be freed, and financing volatility modeled with other distributions; b) the REP in the present paper is not restricted to seek funding under less than minimum efficient scale. Integrating small projects and large projects (such as ones below 1MW capacity and above 1MW capacity), established by many (Mexico’s) regulations to make projects obliged to sell in the wholesale market; c) for lack of readily available data sources, the present research presents in the last section, a brief description of cost reductions by technology, average global investment costs of installations and power flow costs (in US$/MWh), as an indicative insertion to data sources. A further study could use some aggregate but also micro-level data for a quantitative analysis of the subject under study.

All in all, however, the present research project contributes to the project financing literature and understanding of renewable project uptakes and their main hurdles in today’s world.


 

References

 

Bergek, A., Mignon, I., Sundberg, G. 2013. Who invests in renewable electricity production? Empirical evidence and suggestions for further research. Energy Policy: 56, 568–581. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.038

Bieleki, J. 2004. Electricity trade: overview of current flows and infrastructure. In Janusz Bielecki and Leklau Gleboye Desta (eds.). Electricity Trade in Europe, Review of the Economics and Regulatory Challenges. The Hague. Kluwer Law International.

Bolkesjø, T.F., Eltvig, P.T., Nygaard, E. 2014. An econometric analysis of support scheme effects on renewable energy investments in Europe. Energy Procedia, Renewable Energy Research Conference, RERC 2014 58: 2–8. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. egypro.2014.10.401.

Bunn, D.W., and Muñoz, J.I. 2015. Supporting the externality of intermittency in policies for renewable energy. Energy Policy. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.07.036

Bushnell, J. and Novan K. 2018. Setting with the sun: the impacts of renewable energy on wholesale power markets. DEEP WP 020. The University of California at Davis. Accessible at http://deep.ucdavis.edu/uploads/5/6/8/7/56877229/deep_wp020.pdf

Bushnell, J.B., Mansur, E.T. and Saravia, C. 2008. Vertical arrangements, market structure, and competition: an analysis of restructured US electricity markets. American Economic Review 98 (1): 237-266. Available at http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.98.1.237

Carley, S. 2009. State renewable energy electricity policies: an empirical evaluation of effectiveness. Energy Policy: 37, 3071–3081. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.03.062.

CENACE (Centro Nacional de Control de Energía). 2015. Estatuto Orgánico del CENACE. México. http://www.cenace.gob.mx/Paginas/Publicas/MercadoOperacion/Estatutos.aspx

Chassot, S., Hampl, N., Wüstenhagen, R. 2014. When energy policy meets freemarket capitalists: the moderating influence of worldviews on risk perception and renewable energy investment decisions. Energy Research and Social Science: 3, 143–151. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2014.07.013.

Delmas, M.A., Montes-Sancho, M.J. 2011. U.S. state policies for renewable energy: Context and effectiveness. Energy Policy: 39, 2273–2288. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.034.

Egerer and Schill .2014. Power system transformation towards renewables: investment scenarios for Germany. DIW Discussion Papers, No. 1402. Available at http://hdl.handle.net/10419/103366

Egerer, J., Rosellón, J., and Schill, W-P. 2015. Power system transformation toward renewables: an evaluation of regulatory approaches for network expansion.” The Energy Journal 36 (4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5547/01956574.36.4.jege

EIA. 2011. Official Energy Statistics from the U.S. Government. In https://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/us-energy-facts/data-and-statistics.php

Griffin, J.M, and Puller, S.L. 2005. Electricity deregulation choices and challenges. Chicago. The University of Chicago Press.

Harmelink, M., Voogt, M., Cremer, C. 2006. Analysing the effectiveness of renewable energy supporting policies in the European Union. Energy Policy, Renewable Energy Policies in the European Union: 34, 343–351. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2004.08.031.

Höfner, F., and Cranz, S. 2011. Imperfect legal unbundling of monopolistic bottlenecks.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 39: 273-292, at http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs11149-011-9144-5#page-1

Hogan, W., Rosellón, J., and Vogelsang, I. 2010. Toward a combined merchant-regulatory mechanism for electricity transmission expansion.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 38: 113-143. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s1149-010-9123-2

Ibarra-Yunez, A. 2015. Energy reform in Mexico: imperfect unbundling in the electricity sector. Utilities Policy 35: 19-27, at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2015.06.009

Ibarra-Yunez, A., Collins, M., Wright, P. and Zárate, I. 2017. Evolution of the grid to embrace new technologies in the presence of diverse regulatory schemes. http://uc-ciee.org/downloads/FINAL-COPY-Collins-Wright-Ibarra-Zarate_7.6.17_Evolution-of-the-Grid-.pdf

IEA (International Energy Agency). 2018. Data and statistics of power by technology. In https://www.iea.org/data-and-statistics?country=WORLD&fuel=Energy%20supply&indicator=Electricity%20generation%20by%20source

IRENA. 2020. Advancing renewables in developing countries. In https://www.irena.org/publications/2020/Jan/Advancing-renewables-in-developing-countries

IRENA. 2019. Renewable capacity statistics 2019. International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA), Abu Dhabi. In https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/Publication/2019/Mar/IRENA_RE_Capacity_Statistics_2019.pdf

IRENA. 2018. Renewable power: climate-safe energy competes on cost alone. In https://www.irena.org/publications/2018/Dec/Renewable-power-climate-safe-energy-competes-on-cost-alone

Jacobsson, S., Bergek, A., Finon, D., Lauber, V., Mitchell, C., Toke, D., Verbruggen, A. 2009. EU renewable energy support policy: faith or facts? Energy Policy 37: 2143–2146. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.02.043.

Jaffe AB, Newell RG, Stavins RN. 2005. A tale of two market failures: technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics: 54:164–74. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.12.027.

Jamasb, T., and Pollitt, M. 2005. Electricity market reform in the European Union: review of progress toward liberalization & integration. The Energy Journal. European Energy Liberalisation Special Issue. IAEE: 11-41

Joskow, P.L. 2008. Lessons learned from electricity market liberalization. The Energy Journal. Special issue. The future of electricity: Papers in honor of David Newbery: 9-42.

Joskow, P.L. 2005. Patterns of transmission investment. Mimeo. Department of Economics. MIT

Kwoka, J. 2008. Restructuring the U.S. electric power sector: a review of recent studies. Review of Industrial Organization 32 (3): 165-196

Lam, P.T.I, and Law, A.O.K. 2016. Crowdfunding for renewable and sustainable energy projects: an exploratory case study approach. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 60: 11-20. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2016.01.046

Lazard. 2017. Lazard’s levelized cost of energy analysis- version 11.0. In https://www.lazard.com/media/450337/lazard-levelized-cost-of-energy-version-110.pdf

Lesser, J., Su, X. 2008. Design of an economically efficient feed-in tariff structure for renewable energy development. Energy Policy: 36, 981–990. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2007.11.007

Lüthi, S., Prässler, T. 2011. Analyzing policy support instruments and regulatory risk factors for wind energy deployment: a developers’ perspective. Energy Policy: 39, 4876–4892. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.029.

Lüthi, S., Wüstenhagen, R. 2012. The price of policy risk, empirical insights from choice experiments with European photovoltaic project developers. Energy Economics: 34, 1001–1011. At http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.08.007

Martinez Climent, C. 2021. Beyond economic profitability, sustainable financing through crowdfunding. Thesis 7140. Universitat de Valencia. Ciences Economiques. At https://hdl.handle.net/10550/80029

Mathews, J.A., Kidney, S., Mallon, K., Hughes, M. 2010. Mobilizing private finance to drive an energy industrial revolution. Energy Policy: 38, 3263–3265. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.02.030

Mathews, J. A., and Kidney, S. 2012. Financing climate-friendly energy development through bonds. Development Southern Africa: 29, 337-349.  

Matsuyama, K. 1990. Perfect equilibria in the trade liberalization game. The American Economic Review.

Maurer, L.T.A., and Barroso, L.A: 2011. Electricity auctions: an overview of efficient practices (English). A World Bank study. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/114141468265789259/Electricity-auctions-an-overview-of-efficient-practices

Mazzucato, M., and Semieniuk, G. 2017. Financing renewable energy: Who is financing what and why it matters. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 127: 8-22. At  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.05.021

Menz, F.C., Vachon, S. 2006. The effectiveness of different policy regimes for promoting wind power: experiences from the states. Energy Policy: 34, 1786-1796. At  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2004.12.018.

Olmos, L., Ruester, S., Liong, S.-J. 2012. On the selection of financing instruments to push the development of new technologies: application to clean energy technologies. Energy Policy 43: 252–266. At  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. enpol.2012.01.001.

Pollitt, M.G. 2012. Lessons from the history of independent system operators in the energy sector. Energy Policy 47: 32-48. In https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.04.007

Poltzin, F., Migendt, M., Täube, F.A. and von Flotow, P. 2015. Public policy influence on renewable energy investments - a panel data study across OECD countries. Energy Policy 80: 98-111. Available at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.01.026

Polzin, F. 2017. Mobilizing private finance for low-carbon innovation. A systematic review of barriers and solutions. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews: 77, 525–535. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.04.007

Rosellón, J., Myslikova, Z. and Zenon, E. 2011. Incentives for transmission investment in the PJM electricity market: FTRs or regulation (or both?). Utilities Policy 19: 3-13

Stoft, S. 2006. Transmission investment in a deregulated power market.” In F. Leveque (ed.). Competitive Electricity Markets and Sustainability. Cheltenham. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.

THINK Project. 2013. Tender Management System. In https://group.thinkproject.com/en/solutions/project-collaboration/tender-management/

Van den Berg, K. and Tempels, B. 2022. The role of community benefits in community acceptance of multifunctional solar farms in the Netherlands. Land Use Policy: 122. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2022.106344

Wang, S. and Zhou, H. 2002. Staged financing in venture capital: moral hazard and risks. Journal of Corporate Finance 10 (1): 131-155. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0929-1199(02)00045-7

Whitney, A.L. 2014. Clean is the new green: clean energy finance and deployment through green banks. Yale Law and Policy Review: 33, 197- 229.

Wolak, F.A. 2005. Lessons from the California electricity crisis. In James Griffin and Steven Puller (eds.). Electricity deregulation choices and challenges. Chicago. University of Chicago Press.

World Bank. 2013. Financing renewable energy - options for developing financing instruments using public funds. [Online] Available at: https://www.climateinvestmentfunds.org/cif/sites/climateinvestmentfunds.org/files/SREP_financing_instruments_sk_clean2_FINAL_FOR_PRINTING.pdf

Yildiz, Özgür. 2014. Financing renewable energy infrastructures via financial citizen participation: The case of Germany. Renewable energy: 68, 677-685. At https://doi.org/10.1016/j.renene.2014.02.038

Zheng, Y. X., R. Z, Chakraborty N. and Sycara K. 2015. A Crowdfunding model for green energy investment. Conference Paper, Proceedings of International Joint Conference on AI (IJCAI), August 2015.

 



[1] Doctoral Candidate, Fourth Year, Ph.D. program in administrative sciences, EGADE Business School, Tecnológico de Monterrey, Ave. E. Garza Lagüera y Rufino Tamayo, s/n. Col. Valle Oriente, Garza García, NL 66269, corresponding autor, email: cecicascar@gmail.com

[2] Professor emeritus in Economics and public policy, EGADE Business School, Tecnológico de Monterrey, Ave. E. Garza Lagüera y Rufino Tamayo, s/n. Col. Valle Oriente, Garza García, NL 66269, email: aibarra@tec.mx ORCID